A version of this article was first published in the Sydney Morning Herald
If you believe that our growing rate of homelessness is a national shame, or you’re worried that your kids will never become homeowners (or worse, never move out), then we are sorry to tell you, but whoever wins this election, these issues are unlikely to change with the government.
The policies announced by the major parties represent business-as-usual rather transformative housing policy. The Coalition’s Super Home Buyer Scheme lets first-home buyers withdraw up to $50k of their superannuation balance for a mortgage deposit. The same amount needs to be returned to their super account, plus any capital gain, when the property is sold. The ALP’s shared equity plan involves the government “going in” with 10,000 homebuyers per year. To qualify for the scheme you must earn less than $90k per year.
The problem with both of these schemes, as most commentators have noted, is that they put more money in the pockets of homebuyers without adding to the supply.
Suggestions for expanding supply include removing ‘planning red tape,’ and incentivising councils with payments for upzoning to overcome the dreaded NIMBYs.
You’ll hear no argument from us that sharing valuable, accessible land between more people is a good plan. Yes to higher density, transit oriented development.
But these solutions miss something important. They don’t actually deliver affordable supply. They deliver new property rights in the hope that the private sector will deliver supply. But as even the industry will attest, private developers cannot keep building as prices fall.
The private sector also cannot build the supply we need the most – homes affordable to those on disability or parenting payments, homes affordable on JobSeeker, and for key workers priced out by gentrification. These require government subsidy and the Commonwealth receives 80% of our tax revenue.
The phenomenal land price inflation we’ve witnessed this past 12 months has occurred in a context of negative net migration. We have less people to house than we did last year, yet prices have risen sharply. The old supply/demand equation just doesn’t stack up.
House price rises are not symptomatic of a supply problem, unless the supply you are talking about is money (rental increases are another story). As interest rates fell and people found themselves unable to move about, we spent the sloshy dollars on housing. The same phenomenon was observed in other OECD countries, as expansionary monetary policy and covid stimulus was channelled into land and housing.
The housing issues we face today – out of control land price inflation and diminishing access to secure housing tenure – reflect the limits of the private land market. Policies aimed at making private market housing “more accessible” tend to exacerbate price rises and marginalisation overall.
Transformative housing policy is policy that responds to the inherent structure of land markets, shaping and regulating them in ways that reduce rent-seeking for capital gains, reverse or reduce financialisation of housing, and offers non-market housing opportunities.
What do we mean by this?
You make money out of land by dint of ownership. Economic growth, public transport investment, good HSC results at schools nearby – these increase your property’s value without any effort on your part. Unless you intend to develop new housing, property ‘investment’ amounts to chasing capital gains in established neighbourhoods.
Buying and selling land to each other isn’t a very productive way to deploy our capital but nevertheless the 50% Capital Gains Tax discount on property makes it an appealing choice. If you are letting your investment property, weak tenancy protections instantiate renters as a convenience to your wealth building strategy.
The boom/bust cycles we see in property markets are an inherent feature, made catastrophic by financialisation. Recall the GFC. Wall Street took risky mortgages and turned them into tradeable, liquid asset-class. Financialisation abstracts ‘home’ into just another way to make a dime. Minor party, TNL, are tilting at the parliament on a radical definancialisation platform that would tie mortgage lending to a multiple of rental incomes.
If we are serious about supply, then we must fund non-market housing alternatives. This is not only for the proportion of Australians who require a housing subsidy, but also to protect those subsidies into the future. The aim of policy here is to get people off the land price escalator.
Non-market housing includes social housing, which almost everyone agrees needs substantial reinvestment. Non-market housing also includes things like Community Land Trusts (CLTs) and land rent schemes.
These models give first homebuyers, or that growing cohort of older people caught in the inflationary rent trap, secure tenure in a dwelling they own. They are designed to protect any subsidy from the government by regulating resale to below-market prices, and keeping the appreciating land asset in community ownership.
A shared equity scheme with these characteristics has been proposed by the Greens: 125,000 government built homes would be offered to first home buyers, with a requirement that they sell the property back to the trust at a capped rate.
Housing the population is not really a wicked problem. It’s more like vaccinating the population, or educating it. Our governments can fix the housing mess, but they must enact transformative housing policy.
Sad comment, We need the Labour Party to understand and take positive action.
Building more retirement villages would free up family housing and both elements would benefit everyone in the community.
Unfortunately the developers and their derivative retirement village operators are able to generate 2.5 times the return on a normal lease because the 1986 Victorian act written by the uninformed to help the developers get started building villages was extraordinarily biased and once established with government sanctioned seems unassailable.